Issue
Number 15 - November 4, 2002
Printer
Friendly Version
Note:
The size of the type may be changed by clicking on view at the top of
your browser and selecting "text size". The document will
print in the size you select.
Framing
the land issue in Zimbabwe as "white farmers vs. black peasants"
buys into a racial smokescreen about what is at stake. In the U.S.,
that smokescreen is promoted by white-owned media, acting in ironic
alliance with Zimbabwe's president Robert Mugabe. In both cases, though
from opposite sides, obscuring the nature of real democratic land reform
motivates the racial reductionism.
Like Mugabe, the
U.S. media portrays the land issue as purely a racial one. Both put
disproportionate emphasis on white farmers and the racial identity of
owners, at the expense of how land is used and by whom. Zimbabwe's real
land politics are considerably more complicated. A genuinely democratic
approach to land reform would have to take into account social divisions
and claims that race alone cannot capture. As I will suggest later,
democratic land reform would have to address, among others, claims rising
from the history of dispossession, from proximity of communities to
formerly segregated places, and from connection to the soil through
labor.
These issues will
have a familiar ring to many black Americans whose ancestors faced the
dispossessions of enslavement. The broken promise to ex-slaves of a
rooted place on the land they had worked, the legal formalities used
first to bind black sharecroppers to white landowners, then later to
force them from the places where their families had been born and buried,
the manipulation of tax laws and debt to dispossess once again African
Americans who managed to buy land, all resonate with aspects of Zimbabwean
struggles.
Such histories call
up democratic redistribution claims arising from human ties and from
working closely with the land, rather than from the abstractions of
property law and market theory. To see how such an approach differs
from current policy in Zimbabwe, we have to look deeper into current
land politics there.
Land, elections
and parties
A letter to
in issue 13 justifies Robert Mugabe's policies because "majority
rules." Unfortunately that is not true in Zimbabwe.
A majority of Zimbabweans
voted against a new constitution that Mugabe proposed in 2000. It would
have given him enhanced land expropriation powers, and also entrenched
the power of his party, ZANU-PF, and himself. Popular rejection came
even though Mugabe tried to label the opposition organizers of the Movement
for Democratic Change (MDC), headed by trade union leader Morgan Tsvangirai,
as stooges of the white farmers. Undoubtedly the majority of Zimbabweans
want land reform, but when offered this at the cost of broader democratic
rights, they rejected it.
Mugabe since then
has proceeded to act outside the law, to refuse to enforce the law,
and to ignore the Zimbabwean courts (majority African). His re-election
in 2001 was tainted by accusations of fraud and intimidation in the
actual conduct of the vote, though not all observers agreed. What is
incontestable is that the campaign was marked by massive bias, lies
and smears by government-owned media against the opposition MDC and
Tsvangirai personally. The ZANU-PF government controls about half the
newspapers in the country, has a monopoly of television broadcasting,
and most importantly, a near monopoly of radio broadcasting.
Since his re-election
Mugabe has forced through legislation to suppress the independent press.
He and his government continue to organize, encourage and tolerate violent
intimidation of MDC leaders and members, both by official security forces
and ZANU -PF vigilantes. Targets of state human rights abuses include
white farmers, but mostly are Africans. All of this is bad enough, but
today it comes at the expense of confronting a looming agricultural
disaster.
The current
food crisis
Southern Africa,
including Zimbabwe, is suffering severe drought and is threatened with
famine. The Western press decries Mugabe-backed land invasions and attacks
on white farmers, blaming them for the declining production of Zimbabwe's
white-owned commercial farms. Unfortunately, such accounts often are
written as if there is something magical about the whiteness of the
farmers that makes them inherently superior to African farmers, and
makes their farms drought resistant. Conversely, Mugabe's defenders
assert that the famine proves the failure of white-owned commercial
farming and, without evidence, that redistributing the land would lead
to food self-sufficiency and greater national wealth.
Whether or not land
reform could raise productivity, and regardless of the racialism that
can accompany valorization of white farmers, the violent and chaotic
character of ZANU-PF's current course of action certainly has disrupted
the commercial farm system. Even taking into account the drought's effects
on white-owned farms, there is no escaping the fact that grain production
has been massively reduced by ZANU-PF policies in the recent past. Nor
has the commercial farm system been replaced with self-sufficient peasant
production or any other system. Even if some other system could in theory
meet the drought better, the Mugabe-led campaigns have not brought it
into existence, only sabotaged the commercial farm system.
There are some complicated
trade-offs here between direct production for consumption vs. markets
as means to circulate food. Localized self-sufficiency increases peasant
autonomy in good years, but reduces food security in any given place
in bad years, to the extent that food circulation is limited locally.
Markets can bring outside food to hard-hit localities, but often at
a cost premium that poor peasants can't meet, or not without crushing
debt. Likewise the fate of urban Zimbabweans, now a substantial minority
of the population, depends on commercial food circulation. Finally,
there is the (formerly) large role of Zimbabwean commercial agricultural
exports in the national economy and the food systems of nearby nations
to consider.
The implication
of such issues might be that a democratic land reform process ought
to involve a mix of degrees of market orientation, which in turn might
imply a mix of land tenure forms. Or it might be that a case for strongly
peasant-oriented land reform should say how the needs of temporarily
food-insecure localities would be met, along with the regular needs
of cities, and if or how such a system would address the national and
regional role that Zimbabwean commercial agricultural exports used to
play.
Neither ZANU-PF's
approach to the land issue nor the prescriptive straitjackets of abstract
market theory promoted by the international financial institutions can
provide the room for such issues to be debated. Yet such debate is a
prerequisite for democratic land reform.
Who benefits,
and who should?
What then has happened
to land that Mugabe's government has successfully acquired? Most of
it so far has ended up in the hands of Mugabe cronies and ZANU-PF officials,
who continue to hold it as private capitalist property and run it as
commercial farms. The assumption that expropriating white owners means
redistribution to peasants is simply wrong.
In addition to Mugabe's
focus on white ownership, his other rhetorical focus has been "ex-combatants"
or veterans of the Chimurenga liberation war. They are supposed to be
the main beneficiaries of land redistribution. Groups acting in the
name of ex-combatants have been the driving force behind land invasions
and violent attacks on white-owned farms.
However, this ideology
poses several problems. First, a good many of the supposed ex-combatants
are not veterans but simply ZANU-PF adherents. Meanwhile liberation
war veterans who now support the MDC are excluded from land redistribution.
Second, the ideology
contains a massive gender and age bias. Women farmers do the majority
of actual cultivation in Zimbabwe's peasant agriculture. In the nature
of a guerrilla liberation war, women, children and older men formed
crucial elements of the "sea" in which the Chimurenga fighters
"swam," and sometimes bore arms themselves. And women, children
and older men bore most of the brutality of the Rhodesian "counterinsurgency"
campaigns. Yet women are not counted as ex-combatants, and are being
excluded from land redistribution defined and justified in those terms.
Likewise, peasants
and communities in areas of strong Rhodesian government control, who
may have had less opportunity to join guerrilla armies, are disadvantaged,
although they may have an equal or greater historical claim land based
on the history of dispossession.
Finally, the land
invasions are not really attacks on white farmers, but are attacks on
white-owned-farm communities. The majorities of those communities are
African farm workers. Most of the people killed or injured in Mugabe's
land campaigns have been black. You wouldn't know that from the U.S.
press for the most part, of course, because of racially biased focus
on whites.
This is not to say
that white farm-owners do not have fundamental human rights about which
we ought to be concerned, in the face of government-encouraged violence.
But it is to say that when we are concerned for the land rights of Africans
and their ancestors dispossessed by colonialism, and the human rights
of all Zimbabweans, those two concerns do not fall out along the neat
racial lines suggested by both the white-owned U.S. media and Mugabe's
backers. The ZANU-PF government's assaults on human rights encompass
black political opponents, white landowners, and black farm workers
and tenants. Landless participants in land invasions may have a just
claim to land, but they are not the only ones with such claims.
Apart from the being
the targets of violence, the farm workers again raise the question of
who should benefit from real democratic land reform, and who actually
benefits from Mugabe's version. Farm workers have put their sweat and
blood into the land they have worked on behalf the owners, often for
several generations. Some of them descend from communities who owned
the land before colonial expropriation; others are recent migrants to
local areas, or descendants of earlier migrants.
Yet the same is
true of the land invaders. In most cases they do not all come from the
local area. In some cases almost none of them do, when local peasants
tend to support the MDC and Mugabe wants to use land seizure to create
a ZANU-PF presence.
And if a farm ends
up as capitalist private property in the hands of a government minister
or Mugabe crony, the existing farm communities aren't necessarily getting
a better employer or landlord. White owners have been under intense
scrutiny and pressure for "best behavior" that would not be
put on a powerful ZANU-PF owner. There may be ethnic animosity (in the
case of laborers with Mozambiquan ancestry), desire by the new owner
to use the land and jobs for patronage to his own followers, displacing
current workers, and perhaps poor capitalization or inexperience in
commercial farm management, creating pressure to maintain profits through
exploiting workers.
What would democratic
land reform look like?
Real democratic
land reform in Zimbabwe would work very differently than ZANU-PF's partial,
partisan and violent campaign. It would have to be a negotiated process.
It would have to let people to make a variety of claims, recognizing
issues such as historical family ties in an area, current occupation
and work on the land, the right of women to own land they work, claims
of nearby communities, and so on. It would also have to set up terms
on which persons from more distant but overcrowded areas could approach
people in less crowded areas and negotiate joining their communities,
a not uncommon practice in pre-colonial days.
Democratic land
reform also ought to involve strong international pressure on the British
government to live up to its promises to fund land repurchase. Colonial
land expropriation was fundamentally underwritten by British coercive
power. To the extent that current white owners have claims based on
their ancestors' and their own labor and wealth invested in farms with
private property expectations, those claims very largely ought to be
directed to the British government. It was that government which arrogated
to itself, and then granted to Cecil Rhodes' British South Africa Company,
the alleged right to seize the land and to redefine the forms of tenure
in the first place.
Yet even current
white owners ought to have some sort a role and a claim in a locally
democratic process, based partly on length of time their families have
been in the country, and partly on how their black employees and neighbors
view them. This could include a question as to whether the workers and
area residents would want to negotiate some continuing relationship
involving white tenancy and management or other involvement in a commercially
oriented portion of land. Without overstating its significance, it should
be noted that whites who remain in Zimbabwe have shown a commitment
to the country, while many others left, including the most vicious racists
who could not abide the thought of living under a black-led government
(their fantasy Rhodesias can be found on the web by anyone who cares
to look).
Finally, consideration
also ought to be given to the fact that pre-colonial African landholding
was not capitalist private property. It involved multiple overlapping
concurrent use-rights held by numbers of people. Perhaps that principle
could help resolve the frequent situations in which there are multiple
legitimate claims.
Coda: on Robert
Mugabe
Given U.S. media
racial biases, perhaps American supporters of Mugabe are not to be blamed
for seeing Zimbabwe's land issue only in racial terms. But in supporting
Mugabe they are buying into the tacit collusion between his government's
racism and U.S. media racism. These racisms are not the same, but both
are real. Mugabe has power, so even if "racism = prejudice + power,"
Mugabe can be racist. More importantly than his personal views, he and
his government can and do manipulate racial angers and fears, as well
as inter-African ethnic perceptions, as much or more against his black
opponents, and against the interests of the Zimbabwean majority of peasants
and workers, as against the white minority.
Robert Mugabe's
historical role in leading Zimbwabwe's liberation struggle cannot be
denied to him. Possibly the neocolonial restraints placed on him for
two decades, not only by the specific terms of Zimbabwean independence,
but by the neoliberal world economic order imposed globally at nearly
the same time, may have shaped his subsequent slide into bitter and
cynical corruption and towards dictatorship. However, the slaughter
of thousands of people in Ndebele-speaking areas in the southwest of
Zimbabwe by government troops in 1983 might suggest otherwise. Whatever
the cause of his decline, it is a sad sorry damned shame, for Mugabe
and for Zimbabwe. But denying the truth of Mugabe's failures and disintegration,
or the viciously violent character and disastrous consequences of his
recent policies, because he once had a claim to heroism, does no good
for black Zimbabweans, or for progressive thinking about Zimbabwe and
Africa in the U.S.
Chris Lowe lives
in Portland, Oregon and is active with African Action, Washington, DC.
He received a doctorate in African history from Yale University and
lived in Swaziland for 16 months in 1988-89.