Large American cities are in a difficult
economic bind, a bind that is especially tough on poor and working
class Americans, who are disproportionately black and Latino. The
most pressing problem for poor and working class Americans is that
American cities are important nodes in a hyper-competitive global
economy where highly educated, high income workers consistently beat
their poorer counterparts in the marketplace and politics.
The high cost of living in big US cities
is the free market’s way of telling poor and working class people
of all races to leave so as to make room for a vast global pool of
talented workers who want to live and work in urban America. Worse,
the economic logic of the American city forces any urban government
and business community, no matter how progressive, to put the needs
of highly educated, well-off populations – no matter their race,
color, religion or ethnicity – above those of poor and working class
citizens. This bitter class war has a nasty racial aspect but
is, at bottom, primarily about the economic survival of cities, not
race per se.
Does this mean that American cities are
destined to become like their European counterparts, where the well-off
live within the city limits while working class men, women and children
reside in far poorer suburban labor reservations? No, but black
urban politics and public policy thinking must develop a new vision
that marries economic growth to economic justice in ways that enhance
the global competitiveness of cities while creating equal opportunity
for all within city limits. This new urban political economy
in black will also have to abandon racial populism and simple redistribution
if working class urban America is to have a future.
Supply and Demand in the Global City
Modern cities are open trading economies
that grow and stay rich by serving customers all over the world – selling
everything from tourist services like fancy restaurants, museum exhibits,
brilliant instruction at leading universities through financial and
medical services to high quality, specialized manufactured goods. However,
the most important goods and services produced in modern American
cities are high quality goods requiring highly skilled, highly educated
workers. Modestly educated workers still play a vital role
in all processes of production – sales clerks, bus drivers, line
cooks, receptionists, plumbers and carpenters are essential in any
modern society. But workers with low levels of schooling do
not command high wages and bright job prospects compared to their
better-schooled counterparts on Wall Street, Madison Avenue and in
the upper managers’ suites because of the brutal logic of supply
and demand in the global economy. At this moment in history,
there is a nearly insatiable demand for the products of highly educated
workers compared to a still small supply of these people, while exactly
the opposite is true for modestly educated workers.
The inequality between high and low income
workers in cities affects every aspect of city life, locking modestly
educated workers out of opportunities and dividing the city into
warring knowledge classes. Landlords and builders, doctors,
restaurant owners and shop keepers, among others, grow rich by selling
to high-income residents. By contrast, modestly trained workers
are increasingly shut out of all of these markets by virtue of their
low incomes.
The economic problem faced by modestly trained
workers is simple to state and tough to address: workers with low
levels of educational attainment do not produce goods and services
that command a high price in local or global markets, with the consequence
that their incomes are too low for them to get what they need on
their own. This problem lurks behind most of the troubles of urban
America, from affordable housing to unavailable health care, from
crime to bad schools, from chronic unemployment in black and brown
communities to bitter battles over taxes, spending and the direction
of government.
The economy of the modern global city grows
when the number of highly educated, high income workers grows, both
in absolute terms and relative to the number of poorly educated workers. The
business sector of a global city is keen to attract the best and
brightest workers in the world with the promise of a vibrant cultural
and culinary life, safe streets, good public services, a fine housing
stock and low taxes. The business sector also attracts capital
to the city by the promise of a large pool of well-schooled labor,
excellent public services, a large tax base and a low tax rate.
Low-income workers can benefit whenever
the inflow of capital and high income labor creates jobs for modestly
trained workers or improves the quality of shared public goods. The
restaurant boom in major US cities in response to the growing population
of high income workers with cosmopolitan tastes is a major source
of employment for workers with little formal education, just as improvements
in public transit benefit all workers, well and poorly educated alike.
But the knowledge-class divide also leads
to a class war over the distribution of economic rewards in the city
as well as the direction of government. Highly educated workers
have a far more limited need for government to provide jobs, income,
health care, housing or other essential goods than their less-well
off neighbors. Highly educated workers are also less willing
to pay for goods aimed at their poorer neighbors, preferring instead
to use their high after tax incomes for their own purposes. Bemoaning
these high income residents as selfish is beside point: they are
acting in their own self-interest as buyers and voters, just like
poor people who support parties and candidates promising to use government
to redistribute income and opportunity in their direction.
The Perverse Logic of Public Goods in the Global City
The difference between high income and low
income populations in cities amounts to this: if high income populations
do not get their needs met, they leave the city, taking the tax base
with them. Low income populations demand high levels
of city services that can only be paid for by high income populations
that do not need them or want them. Worse, the perverse economic
logic of global cities makes it hard for high and low income populations
to share a city, even when everyone benefits from a large supply
of high quality public goods.
For example, if New York City’s deplorable
public schools were to suddenly turned into brilliant academies for
all of the city’s children, many more people of all colors and classes
would want to live there. But highly educated, high income
families with children would gradually push low income families out
of the city by acquiring an ever greater portion of owner occupied
and rental housing, leading to the terrible situation where improvements
in public schooling lead to the eviction of poor people from New
York. Of course, poor people could stay in New York if better
schools were accompanied by more generous housing subsidies or programs
that boost the supply of low and moderate income housing. However,
this sort of policy would boost the tax rate on high incomes families,
perhaps leading to a gradual exodus of the tax base, diminishing
the capacity of the city to improve either schools or low income
housing.
It is important to remember that the problem
with American global cities is that the economic logic of growth
for cities makes it very hard to redistribute goods and services
to poor and working class residents while promoting economic development.
Consider another perverse aspect of the
economics of bad public schools in a global American city. One of
the many reasons that schools in major American cities are so bad
is that there is a fundamental conflict between the needs of residents
for good schools and the needs of business for good workers. Businesses
in major cities can attract good workers by offering competitive
wages and good working conditions at least so long as cities are
attractive places to work and play. City governments can further
enhance growth by offering high quality public services to highly
educated workers. This means that cities can grow by attracting
workers educated by other governments – whether located in
suburban New Jersey or in New Delhi. By contrast, rebuilding
a solid system of public education is an expensive proposition that
is not likely to bear fruit for many, many years. Why
should the business sector and highly educated residents of a major
city tax themselves to educate the children of their poorer neighbors
when a virtually unlimited supply of highly trained labor is at the
city’s doorstep?
Economic Justice in the Global City
Is there no way out for poor and working
class residents in global cities? Of course there is:
poor and working class men and women in global cities can build a
durable new social contract between themselves and their high income
progressive neighbors – if they pay attention to economic reality
and take a moderately long view of economic development. In
particular, left-leaning, equality enhancing supply side approaches
to public policy can combine economic growth with economic justice
by improving the economic competitiveness of local capital and labor
in the global economy. Further, progressive urban governments
can improve the well-being of poor and working class populations
by using smart policy in conjunction with free markets to make it
lucrative for the private sector to serve hitherto unprofitable populations. In
both cases, progressive government can promote equality and development
by creating the right conditions for widely shared growth across
the knowledge class spectrum, thereby binding the city’s residents
together into a new commonwealth.
The new urban agenda requires everyone to
understand that economic development must be the common project of
all citizens if the city is to become a good place for everyone. In
turn, this means that the city government must find ways to enhance
incentives for all citizens to improve their capacities to compete
in the global economy instead of relying on government to redistribute
money from high to low income residents. The primary goal of
cities under contemporary conditions is to increase the tax base
by bolstering the capacity of residents and businesses to earn the
highest possible incomes. That in turn requires cities to increase
the skills and asset ownership of the vast majority of residents
so that they can earn the highest possible return on their labor
or their property, thereby sharing in the economic bounty flowing
to competitive cities.
The most descriptive label we can assign
to this strategy – progressive development – puts the right emphasis
on the mix of earnings and wealth growth required for the creation
and maintenance of a fair yet competitive city economy. Under
progressive development policy, most forms of government taxation
and spending policies are aimed at increasing the earning capacity
of all workers as well as enhancing asset ownership among low income
populations – particularly home ownership and business development. An
economically sensible city government will do everything it can,
within fiscal reason, to help poorly schooled workers move from low
wage to higher wage jobs through education and job training, as well
as to increase the extent of home ownership among this rising group
of workers.
The key point here is that cities can create
a broad-based investment climate that increases the capacity of all
working adults and business owners to bolster their income earning
capacity. The corollary of this strategy is that governments
do the wrong thing when they devote substantial resources to subsidize
the consumption of populations that either cannot or will not participate
in the investment activity of the community. The contemporary
economic situation of cities is not unlike those of small, trade
dependent countries like Singapore, or when things go very wrong,
Haiti. Singapore grew rich because its citizens and business
sector pursued an aggressive program of skill development, technological
advance and business expansion, thereby allowing the city’s residents
to earn higher incomes in an ever-richer city that could afford more
and better public services as time went by. US cities
can create a climate of growth with widely shared benefits if, but
only if, government supports skill creation, skill enhancement, business
formation and business expansion activities.
The approach advocated here could also be
called the redistributive development state to the degree that government
uses its tax and spending powers to tax high income populations in
order to promote the skill and earning capacities of lower income
and asset poor groups. The flip side of this strategy is that
populations with little or nor capacity to develop greater skills
or earning power will find themselves receiving less attention and
fewer resources, at least in the initial stages of the program. This
situation is not due to any inherent disdain for people who are unable
to earn a living, or who cannot support themselves at a level consistent
with human dignity. Whenever possible, the city government
should try to provide a decent minimum level of support for those
citizens who are truly unable to make it on their own. However,
contemporary economic conditions simply do not permit cities to subsidize
activities that do not create assets or yield a return in the near
or more distant future. An ethical and progressive city
can only provide a real safety net for its weakest citizens when
it is rich and growing, and when the vast majority of its citizens
are truly well-off enough to take care of their weaker neighbors. However,
the weakest among us are obliged to improve ourselves to the greatest
extent possible so that we too can offer our labor, intelligence
and earnings to the common task of building a good city.
So here is the challenge that the economically sophisticated and relevant
urban left faces: build a progressive development society that widens
the circle of home and business ownership, enhances skill development,
creates excellent schools and provides other public goods that can
be widely shared across knowledge class lines while enhancing the well-being
of the City’s poorest and weakest citizens. This is a tall order,
one that will require innovative thinking and political will. It
will also require a black urban leadership class willing to see the
American city as a premier location in a global system that rewards
ability with wealth while punishing weakness and social conflict with
poverty. Above all, the new black political class must
be willing to write a new social contract across the knowledge divide
between highly educated and poorly educated workers, showing everyone
that the cities they love will die unless they build a competent commonwealth
that is fair to all.
Marcellus Andrews is an economist and senior research fellow at
the New America Foundation. Dr. Andrews writes on economic
policy and economic justice for academic and popular audiences, including The
Political Economy of Hope and Fear: Capitalism and the Black Condition
in America (1999, NYU Press) and Taking Back Capitalism:
A Capitalist Road to Economic Justice (forthcoming, NYU Press). Dr.
Andrews received a PhD in economics from Yale University and has
taught economics at Wellesley College as well as the City University
of New York. Contact him at [email protected]